×
Home Companies Industry Politics Money Opinion LoungeMultimedia Science Education Sports TechnologyConsumerSpecialsMint on Sunday
×

Asia and global stagflation

Asia and global stagflation
Comment E-mail Print Share
First Published: Mon, Jun 23 2008. 12 30 AM IST

Illustration: Malay Karmakar / Mint
Illustration: Malay Karmakar / Mint
Updated: Mon, Jun 23 2008. 05 30 PM IST
The world economy is poised on a knife-edge. The US may or may not be technically in a recession, but it is undoubtedly experiencing a sharp growth slowdown. Ireland...the UK, Spain, Portugal, Italy, and the Baltics (that is, nearly everyone in Europe excluding France and Germany) are in a similar position. So much for decoupling.
Illustration: Malay Karmakar / Mint
I am similarly sceptical about the prospects for decoupling in Asia. Asian countries can trade parts and components among themselves all they like — everyone talks about the growth of intra-Asian trade — but they still need someone to buy their final products. And with growth slowing to a standstill in the US and Europe, it is not clear who that someone is.
Credit market turbulence has also affected Asia in negative ways. (More) recently, there have been capital outflows from Thailand, Vietnam and the Philippines. None of this means that growth in Asia will stop, but it does mean that a slowdown is likely. For those who say “there is not much evidence of this yet”, I say, “Just be patient.”
The new development, along with this growth slowdown, is the acceleration of inflation. In April, headline inflation in Asia ex-Japan was 7.5%, a 10-year high (you will remember, of course, what was happening in Asia 10 years ago). Core inflation was 4%.
As for where this inflation came from, it came mainly from the US. Starting last summer, in response to the subprime crisis, the Fed cut interest rates sharply. One can debate whether Bernanke and Co. overdid it, or whether they should have relied more on credit injections at penalty rates; such criticisms have an element of Monday-morning quarterbacking. But whether one agrees with this or not, it is indisputable that those cuts were not appropriate for Asia.
The Asian economy was growing full out in 2007. The last thing it needed was lower interest rates. But that’s what it got, given the habit of limiting the fluctuation of Asian currencies against the dollar. Allowing Asian interest rates to rise more sharply against US rates would have caused Asian currencies to appreciate against the dollar more strongly. And for all their talk of greater exchange rate flexibility, this was not something that Asian governments and central banks were prepared to countenance.
As a result, Asian economies that needed demand restraint got demand stimulus instead. Even without the geopolitical uncertainty, oil-market speculation, bad weather and ethanol programmes that have garnered the headlines, there would have been more inflationary pressure in Asia in the first half of 2008.
Note that this is quite the opposite of the now-fashionable argument that Asia is exporting inflation to the West. To the contrary, the Fed, by cutting interest rates so dramatically, exported inflation to the East. To be sure, the failure of Asian central banks to tighten more aggressively does tend to re-export inflation back to the West. But to start there is to tell only the second half of the story.
What should Asia’s central banks do now? They should raise rates. There have been half-hearted efforts in this direction, but they have not done the job.
It makes no sense when most Asian countries are growing at or near capacity that they should have negative real interest rates. Negative real rates are an unhealthy subsidy for borrowing by households and firms. They encouraged inefficient investment and excessive leverage in Asia in the first half of the 1990s, and we all know what followed.
These negative interest rates and their artificial stimulus to consumption and investment are also why we haven’t seen more of a slowdown in Asia — why we haven’t seen more recoupling. But now that Asian central banks are being forced to tighten, we will see more evidence of their economies slowing. Asian currencies will appreciate against both the dollar and the euro. Although the Fed and the European Central Bank may raise rates as well, both inflation and growth are weaker than in Asia, so they will have reason to respond more moderately.
Critics of inflation-targeting will say that central banks have a dual mandate not just to fight inflation but also to foster growth and that Asian central banks have no business raising rates in a deteriorating growth environment. But the fact of the matter is that they now face a very serious test of credibility, leaving no alternative to tightening. The alternative to painful interest rate increases now will be even more painful increases later.
Fortunately, there is another instrument for sustaining demand in these circumstances, namely, fiscal policy. Higher interest rates will push up the exchange rate and damp down inflation. Tax cuts and increases in public spending on locally produced goods will limit the contraction of aggregate demand. Insofar as these fiscal actions stimulate the demand for locally produced goods, they will push up the exchange rate still further, which will moderate the rise in import prices and further contain inflationary pressure.
Which Asian countries have scope for responding this way? In China, there is likely to be a high return on additional infrastructure investment, especially in the relatively underdeveloped west. There is the need for public spending on reconstruction in the wake of the earthquake. There is the need for increased public expenditure on health care, education and pensions. That the public sector is running a current surplus of 4-6% of GDP (gross domestic product), depending on who is doing the measuring, points to the existence of manoeuvring room.
Elsewhere in Asia, tax cuts and public spending increases should be calibrated to the US and global slowdown — in contrast to the case of China, they should be explicitly temporary. Korea, Malaysia, Singapore and Taiwan are at the top of my list of countries with room to expand public spending temporarily to offset the dampening effects of higher interest rates.
Now, when inflation expectations threaten to become unanchored and the outlook for global growth is increasingly clouded, the need for a change in the Asian policy mix is more urgent than ever.
Barry Eichengreen is professor of economics and political science at the University of California, Berkeley. Published with permission from www.voxeu.org
Comments are welcome at theirview@livemint.com
Comment E-mail Print Share
First Published: Mon, Jun 23 2008. 12 30 AM IST