comScore
Active Stocks
Fri Dec 08 2023 15:59:53
  1. Tata Steel share price
  2. 129.2 -0.62%
  1. HDFC Bank share price
  2. 1,653.1 1.38%
  1. State Bank Of India share price
  2. 614 0.35%
  1. NTPC share price
  2. 285.25 0.42%
  1. ITC share price
  2. 449.15 -1.95%
Business News/ Opinion / Columns/  Smart fiscal policy could help the US Fed do its job properly
Back Back

Smart fiscal policy could help the US Fed do its job properly

Safeguard the central bank from cognitive dissonance on inflation

Interest rates have trended lower in recent years, pushing the Fed’s usual policy rate closer to the zero lower bound.Premium
Interest rates have trended lower in recent years, pushing the Fed’s usual policy rate closer to the zero lower bound.

Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell briskly dispensed with the idea of raising the central bank’s inflation target in his recent speech at Jackson Hole. But the idea isn’t going away. It has influential supporters, and they make a strong case. What’s more, the US central bank could raise the 2% target tacitly while insisting it has done no such thing. This might be the likeliest outcome.

It would be a pity. The better answer is to keep the 2% target and strive to hit it while acknowledging the limits of what the Fed can do on its own. Bringing fiscal policy to bear is the key. If that could be done, the Fed’s job would be easier and the costs of keeping inflation in check would fall.

There are two main arguments in favour of raising the target. The first says the benefit of reducing US inflation from its current headline rate of 3.2% to 2% would be so small that the cost (lost jobs and output at best and maybe a recession) isn’t justified. But this reasoning also applies to raising the target from 3% to 4%, or from 4% to 5%. At each step, the difference in inflation looks trivial and the cost of reversing it is not. This logic says the target is no longer binding, which makes holding inflation at any given level much harder. The second case for a higher target avoids this slippery slope. It says that inflation of 2% is too low, and if the target were a bit higher, it would better serve the US economy.

This view asks, what’s so special about 2%? Few think the ‘price stability’ part of the Fed’s mandate requires zero inflation. What’s needed is inflation low enough to leave economic choices unimpinged. Inflation shouldn’t be ‘salient,’ as the jargon has it. A rate of 3% probably passes this test. And slightly higher inflation has further advantages. It lubricates the labour market by letting real wages adjust gently downward if needed without explicit nominal wage cuts. Most important, by keeping the Fed’s nominal policy rate a bit higher than it otherwise would be, it leaves more space to cut when necessary.

This matters more than it did. Interest rates have trended lower in recent years, pushing the Fed’s usual policy rate closer to the zero lower bound. A slightly higher inflation target would arguably give the Fed an extra percentage point of flexibility on the policy rate at little or no cost. And right now, the higher target would avoid the risk of recession caused by the Fed’s feeling obliged to keep tightening.

The argument is sound in principle, but I’m sceptical on the balance of costs and benefits. If the Fed changed the target to 3%, it would lose some credibility no matter how carefully it explains the move. That could easily outweigh the gain in flexibility. Expected inflation of 3% might well cloud economic choices significantly more than expected inflation of 2%. And if, as some argue, America’s secular decline in interest rates is going into reverse, thanks to demographic forces and/or higher public investment for defence and climate action, the value of more monetary-policy flexibility will be that much less.

It would be better to ask more of fiscal policy. To be sure, the fiscal response to the pandemic wasn’t timid. Rather, it was bigger than needed and unduly prolonged. The Fed has had to raise interest rates as much as it did in part to offset this excessive fiscal stimulus. To moderate the business cycle more effectively, fiscal policy should rely more on automatic stabilizers. It would help if unemployment benefits were made more generous and easier to take up. These and other cyclically sensitive safety-net programmes should reside less with states and more with the federal government. Such changes would help public spending respond more forcefully to the ups and downs of the business cycle.

Plus, the US could follow the example of countries that have set up non-partisan fiscal councils to oversee budget policy. The US Congressional Budget Office could be asked to go beyond reviewing the fiscal outlook and scoring alternative tax and spending changes, and recommend budget changes for counter-cyclical purposes. To cool partisan disputes, this could be neutral, by default, on the balance between taxes and spending; it could propose equal parts higher spending and tax cuts during slowdowns, and spending cuts and higher taxes during booms.

The Fed’s job isn’t getting any easier. If inflation settles in at more than 2%, it will have to weigh the case for higher rates against the risk of recession and sudden financial instability. This dilemma could lead the central bank to cast indefinite tolerance of inflation above 2% as no more than patience in hitting a supposedly unchanged target. It could even come to believe it. ‘Cognitive dissonance meets central banking’ might prove to be the line of least resistance. But it wouldn’t be a good or lasting solution. ©bloomberg

Milestone Alert!
Livemint tops charts as the fastest growing news website in the world 🌏 Click here to know more.

Catch all the Business News, Market News, Breaking News Events and Latest News Updates on Live Mint. Download The Mint News App to get Daily Market Updates.
More Less
Published: 31 Aug 2023, 10:55 PM IST
Next Story footLogo
Recommended For You
Switch to the Mint app for fast and personalized news - Get App